Entrance essay for college
How Can I Write Essay In English
Wednesday, August 26, 2020
Product Selected For the Sales Plan â⬠Free Samples for Students
Question: What Is the Product Selected For the Sales Plan? Answer: Presentation: The item which has been chosen for the business plan is Snickers. It was concocted in 1930 and was a success. It was additionally called Marathon in UK. The bar comprises of peanuts, caramel and nougat with a chocolate covering. It is made by American Company Mars. Objectives: Objective is something that you would like to accomplish. A few objectives are:- 1) To furnish client with quality item. 2) To meet client desire so to guarantee smooth offer of item. 3) To expand the offer of the snickers by making mindfulness among individuals Snickers likewise expects to bring Joy and fun into people groups life. It plans to keep up level of utilization year and year out with little rivalry. 4) To make cost serious items (Makadok and Barney, 2001) Targets: It tells about the firm market openings. The firm focuses available by assessing numerous sorts of market and chooses in which amount fragment it will target. Chocolates are adored by everybody particularly by kids and ladies. Giggle targets essentially to all the age bunches who likes chocolate bars yet it for the most part targets young people and Millennial. A laugh is intended to be for all age bunches it rely on the individuals who love to eat chocolates. Giggles are not all that expensive each and every individual who wants to eat chocolate can bear the cost of it (Sherman, 2017). It is a helpful item which is accessible in all markets and supermarkets. Chuckle likewise utilized old notable big names for their promotions which pulls in the consideration of all the age bunches towards a specific commercial. It is a modest item which can be bought by everybody. It is delicious chocolate bar which can fulfill anybody (Lamb, Hair McDaniel, 2011) Techniques: 1) Snicker started various types of crusade. One of the renowned battle was You are not you, when you are eager. This crusade won honors like IPA grants, AME Awards and furthermore expanded the worldwide deal. 2.) Increase the utilization by focusing on normal chocolate shoppers through producing imprudent and prevailing nearness at retail location. 3.) They are offering astonishing bundling benefits when somebody gets it for uncommon events. Laugh is a noteworthy player in gifting section through event connected blessing packs. 4.) They are giving most extreme client esteem at low cost. Mass buy system is additionally utilized by giggles (Matsuno and Mentzer, 2000). 5.) Snicker is utilizing numerous limited time apparatuses like: - Print media, Social Media, Traditional Media. It kept up authority picture through an unrivaled Marketing Mix. Strategies and Calendar: 1) Advertising CAMPAIGNS January-March 2) Public relations April-July 3) Events August - October 4) Social media crusades November - January 5) Email showcasing January - March References: Matsuno.K.and Mentzer, J.T., (2000). The impacts of system type on showcase direction execution relationship. Diary of showcasing, Vol.64, No.4, pp: - 1 - 16. Makadok . R. what's more, Barney, J.B., (2001). Vital factor knowledge: Application of data financial aspects to technique definition and contender insight, Management Science. Vol.47, No.12, pp: 1621-1638. Sheep, C.W., Hair .J.F., McDaniel, C. (2011).Essentials of promoting, Cengage learning. Sherman, E. (2017). Laughs Manages a Brilliant Marketing Campaign. Recovered on 26 May 2017 from https://www.inc.com/erik-sherman/giggles deals with a-splendid advertising campaign.html.
Saturday, August 22, 2020
Literature Introduction Essay
What Is Literature and Why Do We Study It? â⬠¢ Literature is â⬠Composition that recounts to a story, sensationalizes a circumstance, communicates feelings, investigates and advocates thoughts â⬠Helps us develop by and by and mentally â⬠Provides a target base for information and comprehension â⬠Shapes our objectives and qualities by explaining our own characters, both decidedly and contrarily â⬠Literature makes us human. Sorts â⬠¢ Four kinds of writing: â⬠Prose fiction â⬠¢ Myths, anecdotes, sentiments, books, short stories â⬠Poetry â⬠¢ Open structure and shut structure â⬠¢ Relies on symbolism, non-literal language, sound â⬠Drama. â⬠¢ Made up of discourse and set course â⬠¢ Designed to be performed â⬠Nonfiction composition â⬠¢ News reports, include articles, expositions, publications, reading material, authentic and true to life works Guidelines for Reading Literature â⬠¢ First perusing â⬠Determine what's going on, where, what, who is included, significant characters â⬠Make a record of your responses and reactions â⬠Describe portrayals, occasions, procedures and thoughts â⬠¢ Second perusing â⬠Trace creating designs â⬠Write extended notes about characters, circumstances, activities â⬠Write section depicting your responses and contemplations â⬠Write down inquiries that emerge as you read (in the edges) Composing a Precis â⬠¢ Precis = a compact outline = rework â⬠Retell the features so peruser will know principle areas â⬠Only basic subtleties â⬠they should be right and exact â⬠Must be a unique paper, written in your own words â⬠Be certain to present the title and writer â⬠Avoid decisions â⬠Use current state while retelling a story Elements of Fiction â⬠¢ Essence of fiction = portrayal (the telling) â⬠¢ Elements of fiction = verisimilitude and donnee â⬠Verisimilitude = authenticity â⬠¢ Must be convincing enough that the peruser can ââ¬Å"suspend disbeliefâ⬠â⬠Donnee = premise â⬠¢ Something given by which you can pass judgment on the authenticity = standard procedures. â⬠¢ Sources of components â⬠Character, plot, structure, topic, imagery, style, perspective, tone, incongruity Plot and Structure â⬠¢ Plot = impression of inspiration and causation â⬠No plot = The lord kicked the bucket and afterward the sovereign passed on. â⬠Plot = The ruler passed on, and afterward the sovereign kicked the bucket of pain. â⬠¢ Conflict = controlling drive in an associated example of circumstances and end results â⬠Opposition of at least two individuals (e. g. , contempt, begrudge, outrage, contention, evasion, tattle, lies, battling, and so forth ) â⬠¢ Dilemma = Conflict inside or for one individual â⬠Conflict is a significant component of plot since it excites interest, causes. question, makes pressure, produces intrigue â⬠No strain = no intrigue Structure of Fiction â⬠¢ Structure characterizes the design of the work Crisis Complication Climax Exposition Resolution (outcome) Another auxiliary component utilized at times = Flashback Characters in Fiction â⬠¢ Character = verbal portrayal of an individual â⬠Rounded = similar, full, dynamic, peruser can foresee future conduct on account of a comprehension of the character â⬠Protagonist = the saint or champion, fundamental individual in the story, individual on the journey, and so on â⬠Antagonist = the individual causing the contention, contrary to the hero, the hindrance, and so on. â⬠Flat = no development, static â⬠Stock = agent of a gathering or class (cliché) â⬠Characters uncovered through â⬠¢ Actions Descriptions, both individual and ecological Dramatic explanations and considerations Statements by different characters Statements by the creator talking as narrator, or spectator â⬠Characters need to have verisimilitude, be likely or conceivable Point of View â⬠¢ Refers to speaker, storyteller, persona or voice made by the creator to recount to the story â⬠¢ Point of view relies upon two variables: â⬠Physical circumstance of the storyteller as an eyewitness â⬠Speakerââ¬â¢s scholarly and enthusiastic position â⬠¢ First individual = I, we Second individual = You (remarkable) Third individual = He, she, they (generally normal) Point of view might be: â⬠Dramatic/objective = carefully revealing â⬠Omniscient = all-knowing â⬠Limited omniscient = some knowledge Setting â⬠¢ Setting = a workââ¬â¢s common, fabricated, political, social and transient condition, including everything that characters know and own (place, time, objects) â⬠¢ Major reason = to build up authenticity or verisimilitude, and to arrange a story â⬠¢ Setting makes environment or state of mind â⬠¢ Setting may strengthen characters and topic, so as to set up desires that are something contrary to what happens = incongruity. Tone and Style â⬠¢ Tone = strategies by which journalists and speakers uncover perspectives or emotions â⬠¢ Style = manners by which scholars gather words to recount to the story, to build up a contention, sensationalize the play, make the sonnet â⬠Choice of words in the administration of substance â⬠¢ Essential part of style is phrasing â⬠Formal = standard or exquisite words â⬠Neutral = ordinary standard jargon â⬠Informal = everyday, unsatisfactory language, slang Tone and Style (contââ¬â¢d) â⬠¢ Language might be: â⬠â⬠â⬠â⬠Specific = pictures General = expansive classes Concrete = characteristics of quick observation Abstract = more extensive, less substantial characteristics â⬠¢ Denotation = word implications â⬠¢ Connotation = word proposals â⬠¢ Verbal incongruity = conflicting articulations â⬠One thing stated, inverse is implied â⬠Irony = parody, spoof, mockery, pun â⬠¢ Understatement = doesn't completely depict the significance of a circumstance â⬠intentionally â⬠¢ Hyperbole (exaggeration) = words far in abundance of the circumstance Symbolism and Allegory â⬠¢ Symbolism and purposeful anecdote are modes that grow meaning â⬠¢ Symbol makes an immediate, important condition between: â⬠A particular item, scene, character, or activity â⬠Ideas, qualities, people or lifestyles â⬠¢ Symbols might be: â⬠Cultural (all inclusive) = known by most educated individuals (e. g. , white pigeon, shading dark) â⬠Contextual (authorial) = private, made by the creator Symbolism and Allegory (contââ¬â¢d) â⬠¢ Allegory is an image = complete and independent account (e. g. , ââ¬Å"Young Goodman Brownâ⬠) â⬠¢ Fable = tales about creatures that have human characteristics (e. g. , Aesopââ¬â¢s Fables) â⬠¢ Parable = purposeful anecdote with good or strict twisted (for example , Biblical stories) â⬠¢ Myth = story that encapsulates and systematizes strict, philosophical and social estimations of the human progress in which it is created (e. g. , George Washington slashing down the cherry tree) â⬠¢ Allusion = the utilization of other socially well=known works from the Bible, Greek and Roman folklore, celebrated workmanship, and so forth. Thought or Theme â⬠¢ Idea = aftereffects of general and dynamic reasoning â⬠¢ Literature epitomizes values alongside thoughts â⬠In writing, thoughts identify with importance, translation, clarification and centrality â⬠Ideas are imperative to a comprehension and energy about writing. â⬠¢ Ideas are not as evident as character or setting. It is essential to consider the importance of what youââ¬â¢ve peruse and afterward build up an informative and exhaustive statement. â⬠¢ Theme can be found in any of these: â⬠â⬠â⬠â⬠â⬠Direct proclamations by the authorial voice Direct articulations by a first-individual speaker Dramatic explanations by characters Figurative language, characters who represent thoughts The work itself.
Thursday, August 13, 2020
Add One of These Daily Devotional Books to Your Morning Routine
Add One of These Daily Devotional Books to Your Morning Routine Daily devotionals and devotional books have been a major part of my life since I was a little girl. I watched my mother read hers every morning before she started her day, and she bought me my first one when I was about 15 years old. I didnât always feel as if I connected with the daily lessons when I was younger, but I understood very quickly the power of that quiet time between myself and God. As Iâve gotten older, Iâve kept up the tradition of reading daily devotional books, and usually buy a new one at the beginning of the new year. Over the years, Iâve discovered numerous devotionals, whether 90 or 365 days, that have helped me during different periods of my life. I strongly believe in the power of having a solid morning routine. Spending the first hour or so after I wake in quiet peace and focusing on myself is an essential part of my day. While certain tasks may change depending on the day, a constant part of that routine includes a daily devotional. The Best Daily Devotional Books Whether you want to strengthen your spiritual relationship, are in the middle of a particularly dark time, or are questioning your faith, there are many great options. Here are a few devotional books I recommend adding to your morning routine. Embraced: 100 Devotions to Know God Is Holding You Close by Lysa TerKeurst This 100-day devotional by Lysa Terkeurst combines scriptures, devotions and prayer prompts. As she shares her own personal anecdotes, itâs a reminder to readers who believe that God is always near, fully embracing His children and present through all of lifeâs trials. Itâs an intimate devotional, and through every dayâs lesson it feels like storytime with a friend. Unshakeable: 365 Devotions for Finding Unwavering Strength in Godâs Word by Christine Caine This daily devotional is great for those whose spiritual faith may be wavering in the face of adversity. When times get hard and there may not seem like there is a light at the end of the tunnel, it can become easy for your faith to waver. Unshakeable encourages belief. Destiny Daily Readings: Inspirations for Your Lifes Journey by T.D. Jakes Weâre constantly told to pursue our purpose, but what if weâre unsure of what that is or how to go about doing it? What if weâre afraid of the journey? In Bishop T.D. Jakesâs Destiny: Step into Your Purpose and subsequent devotional, he shares messages in hopes that readers will remain focused on their quest to a destiny fulfilled life. Awaken: 90 Days with the God Who Speaks by Priscilla Shirer When you are alone with God, you have to be prepared to listen and do the necessary work. Priscilla Shirerâs words have a way to jolt you into action and reflection, and her 90-day devotional is no different. She provides passages and thoughts that will encourage and challenge you. She also provides additional scriptures for you to dig deeper and prompts for reflection based on the dayâs passage. Acts of Faith: Meditations for People of Color by Iyanla Vanzant Thereâs always the what-ifs, the should haves, or could havesâ"for many, it is quite difficult to go from maybe I should do this to I have done it. Acts of Faith says to have faith in your abilities, in yourself, in God, and your dreams. Each day of the year has an inspirational quote along with a short essay to induce wisdom and help with reflection. Is a daily devotional a part of your routine? Let me know some of your favorites. Find more of the best Christian audiobooks here to carry with you through your days.
Saturday, May 23, 2020
The Rebellion by Edna in The Awakening by Kate Chopin - Free Essay Example
Sample details Pages: 5 Words: 1415 Downloads: 2 Date added: 2018/12/27 Category Literature Essay Type Book review Level High school Tags: Character Essay Kate Chopin Essay Did you like this example? Introduction A read through the book by Kate Chopin, The Awakening, leaves one with many questions, especially when they are through to the 7th chapter. The story of Edna Pontellier is the one which is problematic, as one follows the character from the beginning of the story to the end. The various transformation of the character Edna is what is sure to leave many questions in the head of a reader. Donââ¬â¢t waste time! Our writers will create an original "The Rebellion by Edna in The Awakening by Kate Chopin" essay for you Create order One might be sure to ask as well as ponder whether this is another feminist novel or whether Edna is mad, or it is, in fact, the author, Chopin who is mad. However, one thing that is sure to stand out in the novel is the rebellious nature of Edna. However, the question of whether her rebellion can be termed to be realistic is one of the factors that many critics of the novel try to argue. In this paper, the uprising of Edna will be discussed as well as the causes for the rebellious nature. Analysis of the Rebellious nature of Edna When a reader first comes across with Edna, she appears to be a muted woman, one who is entirely unable to articulate herself and very much unable to tell a story from her point of view (Urgo 23). However, as one progresses through the novel, Edna gets more courageous and even learns to say no, she slowly turns into a woman who is capable of rebelling as her character begins to take into shape. From the novel, it can be said that awakens Edna as well as her sensuality, is mainly the art of speaking out as well as her being able to make her desires, as well as her emotions, be understood in a narrative form. The awakening is mainly a story about Edna being unable to speak and as such, not being able to make her story being heard. The central tragedy to Edna in The Awakening is that comes to later find out that the story which she is telling is mainly unacceptable in her culture, such demands that if she wants to live in their current society, she will have to silence herself, and igno re the others. However, Edna comes to reject this truth. Such is what brings out her rebellious quality at first. The readers are introduced to the fact that Edna is now willing to extinguish her own life than editing her form of the story. However, such raises a very crucial component in her rebellious nature; she even comes to the point of accepting and reaching for a compromise with death rather than being silent, which seems a very suitable bargain when compared to death. It should be noted that from the start of the novel, Edna is always going through a rough patch when trying to express her emotions as well as experiences in the form of a narrative. A perfect example is when Edna and Robert try to come up with a relation to the ?adventureby Leonce, which they have had out in the water, but they fail. Edna says,It didnt seem half so amusing when told (Chopin 173). Furthermore, one of the most discouraging factors that had been attributed to be causing the turbulence in the Pontellier marriage is the fact that, in the eyes of Leonce, Edna was failing to talk as well as converse with him (Chopin 177). However, the catch is that Edna cant appreciate such type of conversation because the first time the readers are introduced to her, we find her to be mute. All these time, Edna can be said to be quiet, especially for the first six chapters of the novel. Ednas attempt to express herself always runs her into problems; all these can be seen at the first effort to make her thoughts be heard. All this was seen when Edna decided to take anatural aptitude test to undertake to do a painting for Madame Ratignolle. However, when the picture was done, Ratignolle was greatly disappointed as the woman in the picture bore no similarities to her at all. However, Edna interrupts this statement. She says thatIt was a fair enough piece f work, and is satisfying in many ways (Chopin 187). As demonstrated, this indeed becomes the first instance of Edna, having a chance to have her interpretation and thoughts be heard. She refuses to get what she sees as being good, being termed as unrealistic by the other. Such shows that whatever Edna sees in her own eyes, it is not the same that is recognized by her compatriots, such explains one of the causes of her rebellious nature. She is mainly rebellious because she does not conform to the standards as well as patterns of her compatriots. However, Edna destroys the picture despite some consolation from Robert. No sooner had she made the unsettling picture of the Madame Ratignolle than Edna is hit by the many series of her forms of awakenings. With this, the realization the relations that surround her are progressively made more prominent (Chopin 191). The incidence of the painting with Madame Ratignolle teaches her a lot. She learns that even though her visions and way of seeing things are different from the others, it is paramount that she learns to express them. And this serves the second reason for her rebellion, to make herself understood as well as bring out her voice. However, as Chopin explains, the beginnings brought about by such types of awakening are vague, and as a result, Edna still had a very long way in a bid to make her voice be heard. However, it is chapter 7 that reveals much about the history that Edna has concerning her rebellious nature. The section explains the kind in which she would run out of the fields in the sole bid to escape the prayer services that she saw as being gloomy. The chapter also shows why she ended up marrying Leonce as her family had the violent opposition to her marrying a Catholic man. It is evident that she led a dual life all her life as her outward appearance mainly seemed to conform to what the society expects of her while the internal part of her always appear to be questioning the actions she undertakes. Before the life that Edna leads while in marriage, she had experienced various sexual, obsessions as we passionate encounters with some men that he could not have lasting relationships with them. She was always fixated on a writer who was dead as well as having the constant amount of persistence of the infatuation to these other men. Such made it seem like it was genuine love. However, such kind of perception, especially to a dead man, was in a way a perfect portrayal of the weakness that Edna suffered the pain as well of having an unfulfilled love. All these were some of the reasons that aggravated her need to express herself to the world. The story that needs to be told by Edna, as seen, is the story of the awakening that is seen in her body. Such is described by the author asthe animalism that has forever stirred impatiently within her (Chopin 293). Her body has been the one that has suffered more from the silence as it had never found a perfect place to express her desires openly. It is this, however, that he must rebel against, in a bid to set her body and soul free. She must be able to tell her story and be able to explain or narrate her desires to the people, who might sometimes take advantages of her silent and muted nature (McConnell 44). The incident that happens at the Grand Isle, very early in the novel, represents a foreshadowing of the move that will be taken by Edna. That when moving from the appreciation of the passive consumption and appreciation of the arts, towards the side in which it demands active participation, towards the authority as well as the expression of oneself. Such typically represents a move from the viewpoint that the art is taken as being ornamental or just being social to the people of the society. Work Cited Urgo, Joseph R.A Prologue to Rebellion: The Awakeningand the Habit of Self-Expression. The Southern Literary Journal, vol. 20, no. 1, 1987, pp. 22ââ¬Å"32. JSTOR, JSTOR, www.jstor.org/stable/20077844. Chopin, Kate. The Awakening. CreateSpace Independent Publishing Platform, 2017. Print. McConnell, Mikaela. A Lost Sense of Self by Ignoring Other in The Awakening By Kate Chopin. The Explicator 72.1 (2014): 41-44. Web.
Tuesday, May 12, 2020
Essay on Opium Wars - 1685 Words
Drugs have been around for hundreds of years and it modifies normal body functions depending on the drug. During the 19th century, the Chinese had become a victim under the dangerous drug of Opium. When opium was first introduce in China it was like any other drug, addictive and harmful to the human body but the Chinese werenââ¬â¢t aware of the opium negative effects. Opium the narcotic drug is derived of from immature seed pods of poppy plants. Opium was used for pain relieving, it was one of the first drugs able to relieve pain before morphine was invented, and morphine is safer drug then opium and they both came from the same plant. Before the opium war, foreign trade to Western countries was limited and strictly controlled by theâ⬠¦show more contentâ⬠¦Strong economy is very important for every nation, especially in periods of conflicts happening, and with a strong economy countries can support their own military by buying more weapons for better war results. Chinaâ⬠â¢s defeat isnââ¬â¢t just from lack of technology into military but itââ¬â¢s also the insufficient funds to their military. A nationââ¬â¢s military superiority is usually determined by how much the nation is willing to spend on its military; we still see today the superpower of the world like United States is known for its dominating military but their expenditure on military is extremely high which forces their nation in debt. But China is exactly opposite of the modern United States, when they do have money to spend, these money wonââ¬â¢t be used effectively and investing into dead-end ancient weapons like bows and spears. Another misuse of spending for the Chinese government is that they spend too much money on arts and instead on their growing fine goodââ¬â¢s production prospering China a lot during the Opium wars. Though China isolates them away from the rest of the world it does keep a steady economy and the Opium wars triggered an economical boom in China whic h they will slowly prosper. With the treaty of five ports, it welcomes British merchants to do trades with the Chinese and actually benefit both sides. While British are only interest in certainShow MoreRelatedOpium War769 Words à |à 4 PagesOpium War There were two Opium Wars. The first one was from 1839-1842. This war was fought between China and Britain. This war was fought over the two not seeing eye to eye on a lot of things. The second Opium War was from 1856-1860. In this war the British forces fought toward the legalization of the Opium trade. The reason they did this was to be able to expand coolie trace, to be able to open all of China to British merchants, and also to be able to expand foreign imports from internat transitRead MoreOpium Wars1177 Words à |à 5 PagesOpium Wars and They Changed China In the early eighteen hundreds, Britain and other European countries demanded more and more Chinese commodities, especially tea and silk. However, only the port in Canton was opened to foreign countries, and Chinese would not take any other form of payments besides silver. The desire to make China into a free market that foreigners have more access to and the increasing, though illegal, European opium import to China eventually created tension between the EuropeanRead MoreThe Opium War Essay2802 Words à |à 12 Pagesof history which experienced wars, collapses, failures and successes. The Opium War in the year 1839 and 1856 marked the changing point of Chinaââ¬â¢s trade policy with foreigners, especially with British in opium and tea. China changed from getting tributes to being forced to sign the Nanjing Treaty and Tianjing Treaty with British and French. Due to Chinaââ¬â¢s over confidence and unwelcome attitude toward foreigners and opium, it caused the British to declare the Opium War to China which made ChineseRead More opium war Essay462 Words à |à 2 Pages The Opium War was a war fought by two countries Great Britain and china in 1839. The war was fought over the drug opium which was used by the Chinese for hundreds of year to relieve pain. opium is a habit forming narcotic made from the poppy plant. In the late 1700ââ¬â¢s the British was smuggling the drug into China for non-medical use. The navies of the two countries mostly fought the battles of the opium war at sea. Within three years the Chineseââ¬â¢s old ships were simply no matches for the brandRead MoreEssay on Opium Wars in China852 Words à |à 4 PagesOpium Wars in China The Opium Wars were a series of three wars between the Chinese and the British; primarily fought in regard to the illegal trade of opium in China during the 19th century. They manifested the conflicting natures of both nations and demonstrated Chinaââ¬â¢s misconceptions of its own superiority. The Opium Wars resulted in the humiliating defeat of the Chinese to a country they considered to be ââ¬Å"barbariansâ⬠. There were many problems with the system of trade in China; even beforeRead MoreAnti Opium Movement, Opium War And Their Causes2510 Words à |à 11 PagesJoel Palhegyi Final Paper Anti-Opium Movement, Opium War and Their Causes The main theme of 19th century was the imperialism expansion of western capitalistic industrial nations throughout the whole world. During this process, the conflicts between occidental imperialism powers and oriental countries never stopped. The First Opium War, well known as the Opium War, was the war that happened during September, 1839 to Autumn, 1842, between China and Britain. The war was initiated by the conflictsRead MoreThe Opium Wars Of The 19th Century1110 Words à |à 5 PagesJordyn Saito Pacific Basin Prof. Dongyoun Hwang 12/3/16 The Opium Wars Imperial China was one of the greatest civilizations. It was leading in its inventions, trading routes, and craftsmanship. Beginning in 221 BC, it lasted up till the final Qing Dynasty. Itââ¬â¢s downfall can be attributed to the introduction of the drug, opium, from the west. Itââ¬â¢s introduction inspired two wars, namely The Opium wars of the 19th century. In the 18th century, the country was flourishing, while it had controlRead MoreTaking a Look at the Opium War591 Words à |à 2 PagesAmerica and Britain were connected during this time period. Opium was a drug that was originally used for medical purposes, but widely became popular for recreational use in China. The main reason to why Britain traded opium to China was because they needed to find a way to get Chinaââ¬â¢s economy back up and running, and the only way was to trade Opium in China and to get the flow of silver back into the Chinese economy. Even though Opium was used to help the struggling Chinese economy, it became aRead MoreBritish Responsibility For The Opium War1755 Words à |à 8 PagesBritish Responsibility for the Opium War The outcome of the Opium War marked a new age of western imperialism, effectively forcing Chinaââ¬â¢s doors open to the West. How did such a war come about in the first place? At the heart of the conflict lay incompatible market ideologies: Chinaââ¬â¢s interests were in maintaining their traditional tributary system and suppressing the opium trade, while the British desired free trade and diplomatic equality. In a complex storyline filled with misunderstandings andRead MoreThe First Opium War And Its Effects On China1407 Words à |à 6 Pagesexternal, such as the First Opium War. The First Opium war, which lasted from 1839 to 1842, led to several economic and political changes in China. The Opium War is considered more that just a war, the results created a deep impact on China and the Western World. For hundreds of years, China had isolated themselves from the world and from foreign trade, but a single dispute over trading rights led to a huge war, which dictated the future o f China. The first Opium War was because of the trade imbalance
Wednesday, May 6, 2020
Simon Decision Making Free Essays
string(156) " concerned with how people cut problems down to size: how they apply approximate, heuristic techniques to handle complexity that cannot be handled exactly\." Home [pic]http://jayhanson. us/america. htm [pic] Decision Making and Problem Solving by Herbert A. We will write a custom essay sample on Simon Decision Making or any similar topic only for you Order Now Simon and Associates Associates: George B. Dantzig, Robin Hogarth, Charles R. Piott, Howard Raiffa, Thomas C. Schelling, Kennth A. Shepsle, Richard Thaier, Amos Tversky, and Sidney Winter. Simon was educated in political science at the University of Chicago (B. A. , 1936, Ph. D. , 1943). He has held research and faculty positions at the University of California (Berkeley), Illinois Institute of Technology and since 1949, Carnegie Mellon University, where he is the Richard King Mellon University Professor of Computer Science and Psychology. In 1978, he received the Alfred Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences and in 1986 the National Medal of Science. Reprinted with permission from Research Briefings 1986: Report of the Research Briefing Panel on Decision Making and Problem Solving à © 1986 by the National Academy of Sciences. Published by National Academy Press, Washington, DC. Introduction The work of managers, of scientists, of engineers, of lawyersââ¬âthe work that steers the course of society and its economic and governmental organizationsââ¬âis largely work of making decisions and solving problems. It is work of choosing issues that require attention, setting goals, finding or designing suitable courses of action, and evaluating and choosing among alternative actions. The first three of these activitiesââ¬âfixing agendas, setting goals, and designing actionsââ¬âare usually called problem solving; the last, evaluating and choosing, is usually called decision making. Nothing is more important for the well-being of society than that this work be performed effectively, that we address successfully the many problems requiring attention at the national level (the budget and trade deficits, AIDS, national security, the mitigation of earthquake damage), at the level of business organizations (product improvement, efficiency of production, choice of investments), and at the level of our individual lives (choosing a career or a school, buying a house). The abilities and skills that determine the quality of our decisions and problem solutions are stored not only in more than 200 million human heads, but also in tools and machines, and especially today in those machines we call computers. This fund of brains and its attendant machines form the basis of our American ingenuity, an ingenuity that has permitted U. S. society to reach remarkable levels of economic productivity. There are no more promising or important targets for basic scientific research than understanding how human minds, with and without the help of computers, solve problems and make decisions effectively, and improving our problem-solving and decision-making capabilities. In psychology, economics, mathematical statistics, operations research, political science, artificial intelligence, and cognitive science, major research gains have been made during the past half century in understanding problem solving and decision making. The progress already achieved holds forth the promise of exciting new advances that will contribute substantially to our nationââ¬â¢s capacity for dealing intelligently with the range of issues, large and small, that confront us. Much of our existing knowledge about decision making and problem solving, derived from this research, has already been put to use in a wide variety of applications, including procedures used to assess drug safety, inventory control methods for industry, the new expert systems that embody artificial intelligence techniques, procedures for modeling energy and environmental systems, and analyses of the stabilizing or destabilizing effects of alternative defense strategies. Application of the new inventory control techniques, for example, has enabled American corporations to reduce their inventories by hundreds of millions of dollars since World War II without increasing the incidence of stockouts. ) Some of the knowledge gained through the research describes the ways in which people actually go about making decisions and solving problems; some of it prescribes better methods, offering advice for the improvement of the process. Central to the body of prescriptive knowledge about decision making has been the theory of subjective expected utility (SEU), a sophisticated mathematical model of choice that lies at the foundation of most contemporary economics, theoretical statistics, and operations research. SEU theory defines the conditions of perfect utility-maximizing rationality in a world of certainty or in a world in which the probability distributions of all relevant variables can be provided by the decision makers. In spirit, it might be compared with a theory of ideal gases or of frictionless bodies sliding down inclined planes in a vacuum. ) SEU theory deals only with decision making; it has nothing to say about how to frame problems, set goals, or develop new alternatives. Prescriptive theories of choice such as SEU are complemented by empirical research that shows how people actually make decisions (purchasing insurance, voting for political candidates, or investing in securities), and research on the processes people use to solve problems (designing switchgear or finding chemical reaction pathways). This research demonstrates that people solve problems by selective, heuristic search through large problem spaces and large data bases, using means-ends analysis as a principal technique for guiding the search. The expert systems that are now being produced by research on artificial intelligence and applied to such tasks as interpreting oil-well drilling logs or making medical diagnoses are outgrowths of these research findings on human problem solving. What chiefly distinguishes the empirical research on decision making and problem solving from the prescriptive approaches derived from SEU theory is the attention that the former gives to the limits on human rationality. These limits are imposed by the complexity of the world in which we live, the incompleteness and inadequacy of human knowledge, the inconsistencies of individual preference and belief, the conflicts of value among people and groups of people, and the inadequacy of the computations we can carry out, even with the aid of the most powerful computers. The real world of human decisions is not a world of ideal gases, frictionless planes, or vacuums. To bring it within the scope of human thinking powers, we must simplify our problem formulations drastically, even leaving out much or most of what is potentially relevant. The descriptive theory of problem solving and decision making is centrally concerned with how people cut problems down to size: how they apply approximate, heuristic techniques to handle complexity that cannot be handled exactly. You read "Simon Decision Making" in category "Papers" Out of this descriptive theory is emerging an augmented and amended prescriptive theory, one that takes account of the gaps and elements of unrealism in SEU theory by encompassing problem solving as well as choice and demanding only the kinds of knowledge, consistency, and computational power that are attainable in the real world. The growing realization that coping with complexity is central to human decision making strongly influences the directions of research in this domain. Operations research and artificial intelligence are forging powerful new computational tools; at the same time, a new body of mathematical theory is evolving around the topic of computational complexity. Economics, which has traditionally derived both its descriptive and prescriptive approaches from SEU theory, is now paying a great deal of attention to uncertainty and incomplete information; to so-called ââ¬Å"agency theory,â⬠which takes account of the institutional framework within which decisions are made; and to game theory, which seeks to deal with interindividual and intergroup processes in which there is partial conflict of interest. Economists and political scientists are also increasingly buttressing the empirical foundations of their field by studying individual choice behavior directly and by studying behavior in experimentally constructed markets and simulated political structures. The following pages contain a fuller outline of current knowledge about decision making and problem solving and a brief review of current research directions in these fields as well as some of the principal research opportunities. Decision Making SEU THEORY The development of SEU theory was a major intellectual achievement of the first half of this century. It gave for the first time a formally axiomatized statement of what it would mean for an agent to behave in a consistent, rational matter. It assumed that a decision maker possessed a utility function (an ordering by preference among all the possible outcomes of choice), that all the alternatives among which choice could be made were known, and that the consequences of choosing each alternative could be ascertained (or, in the version of the theory that treats of choice under uncertainty, it assumed that a subjective or objective probability distribution of consequences was associated with each alternative). By admitting subjectively assigned probabilities, SEU theory opened the way to fusing subjective opinions with objective data, an approach that can also be used in man-machine decision-making systems. In the probabilistic version of the theory, Bayesââ¬â¢s rule prescribes how people should take account of new information and how they should respond to incomplete information. The assumptions of SEU theory are very strong, permitting correspondingly strong inferences to be made from them. Although the assumptions cannot be satisfied even remotely for most complex situations in the real world, they may be satisfied approximately in some microcosmsââ¬âproblem situations that can be isolated from the worldââ¬â¢s complexity and dealt with independently. For example, the manager of a commercial cattle-feeding operation might isolate the problem of finding the least expensive mix of feeds available in the market that would meet all the nutritional requirements of his cattle. The computational tool of linear programming, which is a powerful method for maximizing goal achievement or minimizing costs while satisfying all kinds of side conditions (in this case, the nutritional requirements), can provide the manager with an optimal feed mixââ¬âoptimal within the limits of approximation of his model to real world conditions. Linear programming and related operations research techniques are now used widely to make decisions whenever a situation that reasonably fits their assumptions can be carved out of its complex surround. These techniques have been especially valuable aids to middle management in dealing with relatively well-structured decision problems. Most of the tools of modern operations researchââ¬ânot only linear programming, but also integer programming, queuing theory, decision trees, and other widely used techniquesââ¬âuse the assumptions of SEU theory. They assume that what is desired is to maximize the achievement of some goal, under specified constraints and assuming that all alternatives and consequences (or their probability distributions) are known. These tools have proven their usefulness in a wide variety of applications. THE LIMITS OF RATIONALITY Operations research tools have also underscored dramatically the limits of SEU theory in dealing with complexity. For example, present and prospective computers are not even powerful enough to provide exact solutions for the problems of optimal scheduling and routing of jobs through a typical factory that manufactures a variety of products using many different tools and machines. And the mere thought of using these computational techniques to determine an optimal national policy for energy production or an optimal economic policy reveals their limits. Computational complexity is not the only factor that limits the literal application of SEU theory. The theory also makes enormous demands on information. For the utility function, the range of available alternatives and the consequences following from each alternative must all be known. Increasingly, research is being directed at decision making that takes realistic account of the compromises and approximations that must be made in order to fit real-world problems to the informational and computational limits of people and computers, as well as to the inconsistencies in their values and perceptions. The study of actual decision processes (for example, the strategies used by corporations to make their investments) reveals massive and unavoidable departures from the framework of SEU theory. The sections that follow describe some of the things that have been learned about choice under various conditions of incomplete information, limited computing power, inconsistency, and institutional constraints on alternatives. Game theory, agency theory, choice under uncertainty, and the theory of markets are a few of the directions of this research, with the aims both of constructing prescriptive theories of broader application and of providing more realistic descriptions and explanations of actual decision making within U. S. economic and political institutions. LIMITED RATIONALITY IN ECONOMIC THEORY Although the limits of human rationality were stressed by some researchers in the 1950s, only recently has there been extensive activity in the field of economics aimed at developing theories that assume less than fully rational choice on the part of business firm managers and other economic agents. The newer theoretical research undertakes to answer such questions as the following: â⬠¢ Are market equilibria altered by the departures of actual choice behavior from the behavior of fully rational agents predicted by SEU theory? Under what circumstances do the processes of competition ââ¬Å"policeâ⬠markets in such a way as to cancel out the effects of the departures from full rationality? â⬠¢ In what ways are the choices made by boundedly rational agents different from those made by fully rational agents? Theories of the firm that assume managers are aiming at ââ¬Å"satisfactoryâ⬠profits or that their concern is to maintain th e firmââ¬â¢s share of market in the industry make quite different predictions about economic equilibrium than those derived from the assumption of profit maximization. Moreover, the classical theory of the firm cannot explain why economic activity is sometimes organized around large business firms and sometimes around contractual networks of individuals or smaller organizations. New theories that take account of differential access of economic agents to information, combined with differences in self-interest, are able to account for these important phenomena, as well as provide explanations for the many forms of contracts that are used in business. Incompleteness and asymmetry of information have been shown to be essential for explaining how individuals and business firms decide when to face uncertainty by insuring, when by hedging, and when by assuming the risk. Most current work in this domain still assumes that economic agents seek to maximize utility, but within limits posed by the incompleteness and uncertainty of the information available to them. An important potential area of research is to discover how choices will be changed if there are other departures from the axioms of rational choiceââ¬âfor example, substituting goals of reaching specified aspiration levels (satisficing) for goals of maximizing. Applying the new assumptions about choice to economics leads to new empirically supported theories about decision making over time. The classical theory of perfect rationality leaves no room for regrets, second thoughts, or ââ¬Å"weakness of will. It cannot explain why many individuals enroll in Christmas savings plans, which earn interest well below the market rate. More generally, it does not lead to correct conclusions about the important social issues of saving and conservation. The effect of pensions and social security on personal saving has been a controversial issue in economics. The standard economic model predicts that an increase in required pension saving will reduce other saving dollar for dollar; behavioral theories, on the other hand, predict a much smaller offset. The empirical evidence indicates that the offset is indeed very small. Another empirical finding is that the method of payment of wages and salaries affects the saving rate. For example, annual bonuses produce a higher saving rate than the same amount of income paid in monthly salaries. This finding implies that saving rates can be influenced by the way compensation is framed. If individuals fail to discount properly for the passage of time, their decisions will not be optimal. For example, air conditioners vary greatly in their energy efficiency; the more efficient models cost more initially but save money over the long run through lower energy consumption. It has been found that consumers, on average, choose air conditioners that imply a discount rate of 25 percent or more per year, much higher than the rates of interest that prevailed at the time of the study. As recently as five years ago, the evidence was thought to be unassailable that markets like the New York Stock Exchange work efficientlyââ¬âthat prices reflect all available information at any given moment in time, so that stock price movements resemble a random walk and contain no systematic information that could be exploited for profit. Recently, however, substantial departures from the behavior predicted by the efficient-market hypothesis have been detected. For example, small firms appear to earn inexplicably high returns on the market prices of their stock, while firms that have very low price-earnings ratios and firms that have lost much of their market value in the recent past also earn abnormally high returns. All of these results are consistent with the empirical finding that decision makers often overreact to new information, in violation of Bayesââ¬â¢s rule. In the same way, it has been found that stock prices are excessively volatileââ¬âthat they fluctuate up and down more rapidly and violently than they would if the marke t were efficient. There has also been a long-standing puzzle as to why firms pay dividends. Considering that dividends are taxed at a higher rate than capital gains, taxpaying investors should prefer, under the assumptions of perfect rationality, that their firms reinvest earnings or repurchase shares instead of paying dividends. (The investors could simply sell some of their appreciated shares to obtain the income they require. The solution to this puzzle also requires models of investors that take account of limits on rationality. THE THEORY OF GAMES In economic, political, and other social situations in which there is actual or potential conflict of interest, especially if it is combined with incomplete information, SEU theory faces special difficulties. In markets in which there are many competitors (e. g. , t he wheat market), each buyer or seller can accept the market price as a ââ¬Å"givenâ⬠that will not be affected materially by the actions of any single individual. Under these conditions, SEU theory makes unambiguous predictions of behavior. However, when a market has only a few suppliers ââ¬âsay, for example, twoââ¬âmatters are quite different. In this case, what it is rational to do depends on what oneââ¬â¢s competitor is going to do, and vice versa. Each supplier may try to outwit the other. What then is the rational decision? The most ambitious attempt to answer questions of this kind was the theory of games, developed by von Neumann and Morgenstern and published in its full form in 1944. But the answers provided by the theory of games are sometimes very puzzling and ambiguous. In many situations, no single course of action dominates all the others; instead, a whole set of possible solutions are all equally consistent with the postulates of rationality. One game that has been studied extensively, both theoretically and empirically, is the Prisonerââ¬â¢s Dilemma. In this game between two players, each has a choice between two actions, one trustful of the other player, the other mistrustful or exploitative. If both players choose the trustful alternative, both receive small rewards. If both choose the exploitative alternative, both are punished. If one chooses the trustful alternative and the other the exploitative alternative, the former is punished much more severely than in the previous case, while the latter receives a substantial reward. If the other playerââ¬â¢s choice is fixed but unknown, it is advantageous for a player to choose the exploitative alternative, for this will give him the best outcome in either case. But if both adopt this reasoning, they will both be punished, whereas they could both receive rewards if they agreed upon the trustful choice (and did not welch on the agreement). The terms of the game have an unsettling resemblance to certain situations in the relations between nations or between a company and the employeesââ¬â¢ union. The resemblance becomes stronger if one imagines the game as being played repeatedly. Analyses of ââ¬Å"rationalâ⬠behavior under assumptions of intended utility maximization support the conclusion that the players will (ought to? ) always make the mistrustful choice. Nevertheless, in laboratory experiments with the game, it is often found that players (even those who are expert in game theory) adopt a ââ¬Å"tit-for-tatâ⬠strategy. That is, each plays the trustful, cooperative strategy as long as his or her partner does the same. If the partner exploits the player on a particular trial, the player then plays the exploitative strategy on the next trial and continues to do so until the partner switches back to the trustful strategy. Under these conditions, the game frequently stabilizes with the players pursuing the mutually trustful strategy and receiving the rewards. With these empirical findings in hand, theorists have recently sought and found some of the conditions for attaining this kind of benign stability. It occurs, for example, if the players set aspirations for a satisfactory reward rather than seeking the maximum reward. This result is consistent with the finding that in many situations, as in the Prisonerââ¬â¢s Dilemma game, people appear to satisfice rather than attempting to optimize. The Prisonerââ¬â¢s Dilemma game illustrates an important point that is beginning to be appreciated by those who do research on decision making. There are so many ways in which actual human behavior can depart from the SEU assumptions that theorists seeking to account for behavior are confronted with an embarrassment of riches. To choose among the many alternative models that could account for the anomalies of choice, extensive empirical research is called forââ¬âto see how people do make their choices, what beliefs guide them, what information they have available, and what part of that information they take into account and what part they ignore. In a world of limited rationality, economics and the other decision sciences must closely examine the actual limits on rationality in order to make accurate predictions and to provide sound advice on public policy. EMPIRICAL STUDIES OF CHOICE UNDER UNCERTAINTY During the past ten years, empirical studies of human choices in which uncertainty, inconsistency, and incomplete information are present have produced a rich collection of findings which only now are beginning to be organized under broad generalizations. Here are a few examples. When people are given information about the probabilities of certain events (e. g. , how many lawyers and how many engineers are in a population that is being sampled), and then are given some additional information as to which of the vents has occurred (which person has been sampled from the population), they tend to ignore the prior probabilities in favor of incomplete or even quite irrelevant information about the individual event. Thus, if they are told that 70 percent of the population are lawyers, and if they are then given a noncommittal description of a person (one that could equally well fit a lawyer or an engineer), half the time they will predict that the person is a lawyer and half the time that he is an engineerââ¬âeven though the laws of probability dictate that the best forecast is always to predict that the person is a lawyer. People commonly misjudge probabilities in many other ways. Asked to estimate the probability that 60 percent or more of the babies born in a hospital during a given week are male, they ignore information about the total number of births, although it is evident that the probability of a departure of this magnitude from the expected value of 50 percent is smaller if the total number of births is larger (the standard error of a percentage varies inversely with the square root of the population size). There are situations in which people assess the frequency of a class by the ease with which instances can be brought to mind. In one experiment, subjects heard a list of names of persons of both sexes and were later asked to judge whether there were more names of men or women on the list. In lists presented to some subjects, the men were more famous than the women; in other lists, the women were more famous than the men. For all lists, subjects judged that the sex that had the more famous personalities was the more numerous. The way in which an uncertain possibility is presented may have a substantial effect on how people respond to it. When asked whether they would choose surgery in a hypothetical medical emergency, many more people said that they would when the chance of survival was given as 80 percent than when the chance of death was given as 20 percent. On the basis of these studies, some of the general heuristics, or rules of thumb, that people use in making judgments have been compiledââ¬âheuristics that produce biases toward classifying situations according to their representativeness, or toward judging frequencies according to the availability of examples in memory, or toward interpretations warped by the way in which a problem has been framed. These findings have important implications for public policy. A recent example is the lobbying effort of the credit card industry to have differentials between cash and credit prices labeled ââ¬Å"cash discountsâ⬠rather than ââ¬Å"credit surcharges. â⬠The research findings raise questions about how to phrase cigarette warning labels or frame truth-in-lending laws and informed consent laws. METHODS OF EMPIRICAL RESEARCH Finding the underlying bases of human choice behavior is difficult. People cannot always, or perhaps even usually, provide veridical accounts of how they make up their minds, especially when there is uncertainty. In many cases, they can predict how they will behave (pre-election polls of voting intentions have been reasonably accurate when carefully taken), but the reasons people give for their choices can often be shown to be rationalizations and not closely related to their real motives. Students of choice behavior have steadily improved their research methods. They question respondents about specific situations, rather than asking for generalizations. They are sensitive to the dependence of answers on the exact forms of the questions. They are aware that behavior in an experimental situation may be different from behavior in real life, and they attempt to provide experimental settings and motivations that are as realistic as possible. Using thinking-aloud protocols and other approaches, they try to track the choice behavior step by step, instead of relying just on information about outcomes or querying respondents retrospectively about their choice processes. Perhaps the most common method of empirical research in this field is still to ask people to respond to a series of questions. But data obtained by this method are being supplemented by data obtained from carefully designed laboratory experiments and from observations of actual choice behavior (for example, the behavior of customers in supermarkets). In an experimental study of choice, subjects may trade in an actual market with real (if modest) monetary rewards and penalties. Research experience has also demonstrated the feasibility of making direct observations, over substantial periods of time, of the decision-making processes in business and governmental organizationsââ¬âfor example, observations of the procedures that corporations use in making new investments in plant and equipment. Confidence in the empirical findings that have been accumulating over the past several decades is enhanced by the general consistency that is observed among the data obtained from quite different settings using different research methods. There still remains the enormous and challenging task of putting together these findings into an empirically founded theory of decision making. With the growing availability of data, the theory-building enterprise is receiving much better guidance from the facts than it did in the past. As a result, we can expect it to become correspondingly more effective in arriving at realistic models of behavior. Problem Solving The theory of choice has its roots mainly in economics, statistics, and operations research and only recently has received much attention from psychologists; the theory of problem solving has a very different history. Problem solving was initially studied principally by psychologists, and more recently by researchers in artificial intelligence. It has received rather scant attention from economists. CONTEMPORARY PROBLEM-SOLVING THEORY Human problem solving is usually studied in laboratory settings, using problems that can be solved in relatively short periods of time (seldom more than an hour), and often seeking a maximum density of data about the solution process by asking subjects to think aloud while they work. The thinking-aloud technique, at first viewed with suspicion by behaviorists as subjective and ââ¬Å"introspective,â⬠has received such careful methodological attention in recent years that it can now be used dependably to obtain data about subjectsââ¬â¢ behaviors in a wide range of settings. The laboratory study of problem solving has been supplemented by field studies of professionals solving real-world problemsââ¬âfor example, physicians making diagnoses and chess grandmasters analyzing game positions, and, as noted earlier, even business corporations making investment decisions. Currently, historical records, including laboratory notebooks of scientists, are also being used to study problem-solving processes in scientific discovery. Although such records are far less ââ¬Å"denseâ⬠than laboratory protocols, they sometimes permit the course of discovery to be traced in considerable detail. Laboratory notebooks of scientists as distinguished as Charles Darwin, Michael Faraday, Antoine-Laurent Lavoisier, and Hans Krebs have been used successfully in such research. From empirical studies, a description can now be given of the problem-solving process that holds for a rather wide range of activities. First, problem solving generally proceeds by selective search through large sets of possibilities, using rules of thumb (heuristics) to guide the search. Because the possibilities in realistic problem situations are generally multitudinous, trial-and-error search would simply not work; the search must be highly selective. Chess grandmasters seldom examine more than a hundred of the vast number of possible scenarios that confront them, and similar small numbers of searches are observed in other kinds of problem-solving search. One of the procedures often used to guide search is ââ¬Å"hill climbing,â⬠using some measure of approach to the goal to determine where it is most profitable to look next. Another, and more powerful, common procedure is means-ends analysis. In means-ends analysis, the problem solver compares the present situation with the goal, detects a difference between them, and then searches memory for actions that are likely to reduce the difference. Thus, if the difference is a fifty-mile distance from the goal, the problem solver will retrieve from memory knowledge about autos, carts, bicycles, and other means of transport; walking and flying will probably be discarded as inappropriate for that distance. The third thing that has been learned about problem solvingââ¬âespecially when the solver is an expertââ¬âis that it relies on large amounts of information that are stored in memory and that are retrievable whenever the solver recognizes cues signaling its relevance. Thus, the expert knowledge of a diagnostician is evoked by the symptoms presented by the patient; this knowledge leads to the recollection of what additional information is needed to discriminate among alternative diseases and, finally, to the diagnosis. In a few cases, it has been possible to estimate how many patterns an expert must be able to recognize in order to gain access to the relevant knowledge stored in memory. A chess master must be able to recognize about 50,000 different configurations of chess pieces that occur frequently in the course of chess games. A medical diagnostician must be able to recognize tens of thousands of configurations of symptoms; a botanist or zoologist specializing in taxonomy, tens or hundreds of thousands of features of specimens that define their species. For comparison, college graduates typically have vocabularies in their native languages of 50,000 to 200,000 words. (However, these numbers are very small in comparison with the real-world situations the expert faces: there are perhaps 10120 branches in the game tree of chess, a game played with only six kinds of pieces on an 8 x 8 board. One of the accomplishments of the contemporary theory of problem solving has been to provide an explanation for the phenomena of intuition and judgment frequently seen in expertsââ¬â¢ behavior. The store of expert knowledge, ââ¬Å"indexedâ⬠by the recognition cues that make it accessible and combined with some basic inferential capabilities (perhaps in the form of means-ends analysis), accounts for the ability of experts to find satisfactory solutions for difficult problems, and sometimes to find them almost instantaneously. The expertââ¬â¢s ââ¬Å"intuitionâ⬠and ââ¬Å"judgmentâ⬠derive from this capability for rapid recognition linked to a large store of knowledge. When immediate intuition fails to yield a problem solution or when a prospective solution needs to be evaluated, the expert falls back on the slower processes of analysis and inference. EXPERT SYSTEMS IN ARTIFICIAL INTELLIGENCE Over the past thirty years, there has been close teamwork between research in psychology and research in computer science aimed at developing intelligent programs. Artificial intelligence (AI) research has both borrowed from and contributed to research on human problem solving. Today, artificial intelligence is beginning to produce systems, applied to a variety of tasks, that can solve difficult problems at the level of professionally trained humans. These AI programs are usually called expert systems. A description of a typical expert system would resemble closely the description given above of typical human problem solving; the differences between the two would be differences in degree, not in kind. An AI expert system, relying on the speed of computers and their ability to retain large bodies of transient information in memory, will generally use ââ¬Å"brute forceâ⬠ââ¬âsheer omputational speed and powerââ¬âmore freely than a human expert can. A human expert, in compensation, will generally have a richer set of heuristics to guide search and a larger vocabulary of recognizable patterns. To the observer, the computerââ¬â¢s process will appear the more systematic and even compulsive, the humanââ¬â¢s the more intuitive. But these are quan titative, not qualitative, differences. The number of tasks for which expert systems have been built is increasing rapidly. One is medical diagnosis (two examples are the CADUCEUS and MYCIN programs). Others are automatic design of electric motors, generators, and transformers (which predates by a decade the invention of the term expert systems), the configuration of computer systems from customer specifications, and the automatic generation of reaction paths for the synthesis of organic molecules. All of these (and others) are either being used currently in professional or industrial practice or at least have reached a level at which they can produce a professionally acceptable product. Expert systems are generally constructed in close consultation with the people who are experts in the task domain. Using standard techniques of observation and interrogation, the heuristics that the human expert uses, implicitly and often unconsciously, to perform the task are gradually educed, made explicit, and incorporated in program structures. Although a great deal has been learned about how to do this, improving techniques for designing expert systems is an important current direction of research. It is especially important because expert systems, once built, cannot remain static but must be modifiable to incorporate new knowledge as it becomes available. DEALING WITH ILL-STRUCTURED PROBLEMS In the 1950s and 1960s, research on problem solving focused on clearly structured puzzle-like problems that were easily brought into the psychological laboratory and that were within the range of computer programming sophistication at that time. Computer programs were written to discover proofs for theorems in Euclidean geometry or to solve the puzzle of transporting missionaries and cannibals across a river. Choosing chess moves was perhaps the most complex task that received attention in the early years of cognitive science and AI. As understanding grew of the methods needed to handle these relatively simple tasks, research aspirations rose. The next main target, in the 1960s and 1970s, was to find methods for solving problems that involved large bodies of semantic information. Medical diagnosis and interpreting mass spectrogram data are examples of the kinds of tasks that were investigated during this period and for which a good level of understanding was achieved. They are tasks that, for all of the knowledge they call upon, are still well structured, with clear-cut goals and constraints. The current research target is to gain an understanding of problem-solving tasks when the goals themselves are complex and sometimes ill defined, and when the very nature of the problem is successively transformed in the course of exploration. To the extent that a problem has these characteristics, it is usually called ill structured. Because ambiguous goals and shifting problem formulations are typical characteristics of problems of design, the work of architects offers a good example of what is involved in solving ill-structured problems. An architect begins with some very general specifications of what is wanted by a client. The initial goals are modified and substantially elaborated as the architect proceeds with the task. Initial design ideas, recorded in drawings and diagrams, themselves suggest new criteria, new possibilities, and new requirements. Throughout the whole process of design, the emerging conception provides continual feedback that reminds the architect of additional considerations that need to be taken into account. With the current state of the art, it is just beginning to be possible to construct programs that simulate this kind of flexible problem-solving process. What is called for is an expert system whose expertise includes substantial knowledge about design criteria as well as knowledge about the means for satisfying those criteria. Both kinds of knowledge are evoked in the course of the design activity by the usual recognition processes, and the evocation of design criteria and constraints continually modifies and remolds the problem that the design system is addressing. The large data bases that can now be constructed to aid in the management of architectural and construction projects provide a framework into which AI tools, fashioned along these lines, can be incorporated. Most corporate strategy problems and governmental policy problems are at least as ill structured as problems of architectural or engineering design. The tools now being forged for aiding architectural design will provide a basis for building tools that can aid in formulating, assessing, and monitoring public energy or environmental policies, or in guiding corporate product and investment strategies. SETTING THE AGENDA AND REPRESENTING A PROBLEM The very first steps in the problem-solving process are the least understood. What brings (and should bring) problems to the head of the agenda? And when a problem is identified, how can it be represented in a way that facilitates its solution? The task of setting an agenda is of utmost importance because both individual human beings and human institutions have limited capacities for dealing with many tasks simultaneously. While some problems are receiving full attention, others are neglected. Where new problems come thick and fast, ââ¬Å"fire fightingâ⬠replaces planning and deliberation. The facts of limited attention span, both for individuals and for institutions like the Congress, are well known. However, relatively little has been accomplished toward analyzing or designing effective agenda-setting systems. A beginning could be made by the study of ââ¬Å"alertingâ⬠organizations like the Office of Technology Assessment or military and foreign affairs intelligence agencies. Because the research and development function in industry is also in considerable part a task of monitoring current and prospective technological advances, it could also be studied profitably from this standpoint. The way in which problems are represented has much to do with the quality of the solutions that are found. The task of designing highways or dams takes on an entirely new aspect if human responses to a changed environment are taken into account. (New transportation routes cause people to move their homes, and people show a considerable propensity to move into zones that are subject to flooding when partial protections are erected. Very different social welfare policies are usually proposed in response to the problem of providing incentives for economic independence than are proposed in response to the problem of taking care of the needy. Early management information systems were designed on the assumption that information was the scarce resource; today, because designers re cognize that the scarce resource is managerial attention, a new framework produces quite different designs. The representation or ââ¬Å"framingâ⬠of problems is even less well understood than agenda setting. Todayââ¬â¢s expert systems make use of problem representations that already exist. But major advances in human knowledge frequently derive from new ways of thinking about problems. A large part of the history of physics in nineteenth-century England can be written in terms of the shift from action-at-a-distance representations to the field representations that were developed by the applied mathematicians at Cambridge. Today, developments in computer-aided design (CAD) present new opportunities to provide human designers with computer-generated representations of their problems. Effective use of these capabilities requires us to understand better how people extract information from diagrams and other displays and how displays can enhance human performance in design tasks. Research on representations is fundamental to the progress of CAD. COMPUTATION AS PROBLEM SOLVING Nothing has been said so far about the radical changes that have been brought about in problem solving over most of the domains of science and engineering by the standard uses of computers as computational devices. Although a few examples come to mind in which artificial intelligence has contributed to these developments, they have mainly been brought about by research in the individual sciences themselves, combined with work in numerical analysis. Whatever their origins, the massive computational applications of computers are changing the conduct of science in numerous ways. There are new specialties emerging such as ââ¬Å"computational physicsâ⬠and ââ¬Å"computational chemistry. Computationââ¬âthat is to say, problem solvingââ¬âbecomes an object of explicit concern to scientists, side by side with the substance of the science itself. Out of this new awareness of the computational component of scientific inquiry is arising an increasing interaction among computational specialists in the various sciences and scientists concerned with cognition and AI. This interaction extends well beyond the traditional area of numerical analysis, or even the newer subject of computational compl exity, into the heart of the theory of problem solving. Physicists seeking to handle the great mass of bubble-chamber data produced by their instruments began, as early as the 1960s, to look to AI for pattern recognition methods as a basis for automating the analysis of their data. The construction of expert systems to interpret mass spectrogram data and of other systems to design synthesis paths for chemical reactions are other examples of problem solving in science, as are programs to aid in matching sequences of nucleic acids in DNA and RNA and amino acid sequences in proteins. Theories of human problem solving and learning are also beginning to attract new attention within the scientific community as a basis for improving science teaching. Each advance in the understanding of problem solving and learning processes provides new insights about the ways in which a learner must store and index new knowledge and procedures if they are to be useful for solving problems. Research on these topics is also generating new ideas about how effective learning takes placeââ¬âfor example, how students can learn by examining and analyzing worked-out examples. Extensions of Theory Opportunities for advancing our understanding of decision making and problem solving are not limited to the topics dealt with above, and in this section, just a few indications of additional promising directions for research are presented. DECISION MAKING OVER TIME The time dimension is especially troublesome in decision making. Economics has long used the notion of time discounting and interest rates to compare present with future consequences of decisions, but as noted above, research on actual decision making shows that people frequently are inconsistent in their choices between present and future. Although time discounting is a powerful idea, it requires fixing appropriate discount rates for individual, and especially social, decisions. Additional problems arise because human tastes and priorities change over time. Classical SEU theory assumes a fixed, consistent utility function, which does not easily accommodate changes in taste. At the other extreme, theories postulating a limited attention span do not have ready ways of ensuring consistency of choice over time. AGGREGATION In applying our knowledge of decision making and problem solving to society-wide, or even organization-wide, phenomena, the problem of aggregation must be solved; that is, ways must be found to extrapolate from theories of individual decision processes to the net effects on the whole economy, polity, and society. Because of the wide variety of ways in which any given decision task can be approached, it is unrealistic to postulate a ââ¬Å"representative firmâ⬠or an ââ¬Å"economic man,â⬠and to simply lump together the behaviors of large numbers of supposedly identical individuals. Solving the aggregation problem becomes more important as more of the empirical research effort is directed toward studying behavior at a detailed, microscopic level. ORGANIZATIONS Related to aggregation is the question of how decision making and problem solving change when attention turns from the behavior of isolated individuals to the behavior of these same individuals operating as members of organizations or other groups. When people assume organizational positions, they adapt their goals and values to their responsibilities. Moreover, their decisions are influenced substantially by the patterns of information flow and other communications among the various organization units. Organizations sometimes display sophisticated capabilities far beyond the understanding of single individuals. They sometimes make enormous blunders or find themselves incapable of acting. Organizational performance is highly sensitive to the quality of the routines or ââ¬Å"performance programsâ⬠that govern behavior and to the adaptability of these routines in the face of a changing environment. In particular, the ââ¬Å"peripheral visionâ⬠of a complex organization is limited, so that responses to novelty in the environment may be made in inappropriate and quasi-automatic ways that cause major failure. Theory development, formal modeling, laboratory experiments, and analysis of historical cases are all going forward in this important area of inquiry. Although the decision-making processes of organizations have been studied in the field on a limited scale, a great many more such intensive studies will be needed before the full range of techniques used by organizations to make their decisions is understood, and before the strengths and weaknesses of these techniques are grasped. LEARNING Until quite recently, most research in cognitive science and artificial intelligence had been aimed at understanding how intelligent systems perform their work. Only in the past five years has attention begun to turn to the question of how systems become intelligentââ¬âhow they learn. A number of promising hypotheses about learning mechanisms are currently being explored. One is the so-called connexionist hypothesis, which postulates networks that learn by changing the strengths of their interconnections in response to feedback. Another learning mechanism that is being investigated is the adaptive production system, a computer program that learns by generating new instructions that are simply annexed to the existing program. Some success has been achieved in constructing adaptive production systems that can learn to solve equations in algebra and to do other tasks at comparable levels of difficulty. Learning is of particular importance for successful adaptation to an environment that is changing rapidly. Because that is exactly the environment of the 1980s, the trend toward broadening research on decision making to include learning and adaptation is welcome. This section has by no means exhausted the areas in which exciting and important research can be launched to deepen understanding of decision making and problem solving. But perhaps the examples that have been provided are sufficient to convey the promise and significance of this field of inquiry today. Current Research Programs Most of the current research on decision making and problem solving is carried on in universities, frequently with the support of government funding agencies and private foundations. Some research is done by consulting firms in connection with their development and application of the tools of operations research, artificial intelligence, and systems modeling. In some cases, government agencies and corporations have supported the development of planning models to aid them in their policy planningââ¬âfor example, corporate strategic planning for investments and markets and government planning of environmental and energy policies. There is an increasing number of cases in which research scientists are devoting substantial attention to improving the problem-solving and decision-making tools in their disciplines, as we noted in the examples of automation of the processing of bubble-chamber tracks and of the interpretation of mass spectrogram data. To use a generous estimate, support for basic research in the areas described in this document is probably at the level of tens of millions of dollars per year, and almost certainly, it is not as much as $100 million. The principal costs are for research personnel and computing equipment, the former being considerably larger. Because of the interdisciplinary character of the research domain, federal research support comes from a number of different agencies, and it is not easy to assess the total picture. Within the National Science Foundation (NSF), the grants of the decision and management sciences, political science and the economics programs in the Social Sciences Division are to a considerable extent devoted to projects in this domain. Smaller amounts of support come from the memory and cognitive processes program in the Division of Behavioral and Neural Sciences, and perhaps from other programs. The ââ¬Å"softwareâ⬠component of the new NSF Directorate of Computer Science and Engineering contains programs that have also provided important support to the study of decision making and problem solving. The Office of Naval Research has, over the years, supported a wide range of studies of decision making, including important early support for operations research. The main source of funding for research in AI has been the Defense Advanced Research Projects Agency (DARPA) in the Department of Defense; important support for research on applications of A1 to medicine has been provided by the National Institutes of Health. Relevant economics research is also funded by other federal agencies, including the Treasury Department, the Bureau of Labor Statistics, and the Federal Reserve Board. In recent years, basic studies of decision making have received only relatively minor support from these sources, but because of the relevance of the research to their missions, they could become major sponsors. Although a number of projects have been and are funded by private foundations, there appears to be at present no foundation for which decision making and problem solving are a major focus of interest. In sum, the pattern of support for research in this field shows a healthy diversity but no agency with a clear lead responsibility, unless it be the rather modestly funded program in decision and management sciences at NSF. Perhaps the largest scale of support has been provided by DARPA, where decision making and problem solving are only components within the larger area of artificial intelligence and certainly not highly visible research targets. The character of the funding requirements in this domain is much the same as in other fields of research. A rather intensive use of computational facilities is typical of most, but not all, of the research. And because the field is gaining new recognition and growing rapidly, there are special needs for the support of graduate students and postdoctoral training. In the computing-intensive part of the domain, desirable research funding per principal investigator might average $250,000 per year; in empirical research involving field studies and large-scale experiments, a similar amount; and in other areas of theory and laboratory experimentation, somewhat less. Research Opportunities: Summary The study of decision making and problem solving has attracted much attention through most of this century. By the end of World War II, a powerful prescriptive theory of rationality, the theory of subjective expected utility (SEU), had taken form; it was followed by the theory of games. The past forty years have seen widespread applications of these theories in economics, operations research, and statistics, and, through these disciplines, to decision making in business and government. The main limitations of SEU theory and the developments based on it are its relative neglect of the limits of human (and computer) problem-solving capabilities in the face of real-world complexity. Recognition of these limitations has produced an increasing volume of empirical research aimed at discovering how humans cope with complexity and reconcile it with their bounded computational powers. Recognition that human rationality is limited occasions no surprise. What is surprising are some of the forms these limits take and the kinds of departures from the behavior predicted by the SEU model that have been observed. Extending empirical knowledge of actual human cognitive processes and of techniques for dealing with complexity continues to be a research goal of very high priority. Such empirical knowledge is needed both to build valid theories of how the U. S. society and economy operate and to build prescriptive tools for decision making that are compatible with existing computational capabilities. The complementary fields of cognitive psychology and artificial intelligence have produced in the past thirty years a fairly well-developed theory of problem solving that lends itself well to computer simulation, both for purposes of testing its empirical validity and for augmenting human problem-solving capacities by the construction of expert systems. Problem-solving research today is being extended into the domain of ill-structured problems and applied to the task of formulating problem representations. The processes for setting the problem agenda, which are still very little explored, deserve more research attention. The growing importance of computational techniques in all of the sciences has attracted new attention to numerical analysis and to the topic of computational complexity. The need to use heuristic as well as rigorous methods for analyzing very complex domains is beginning to bring about a wide interest, in various sciences, in the possible application of problem-solving theories to computation. Opportunities abound for productive research in decision making and problem solving. A few of the directions of research that look especially promising and significant follow: â⬠¢ A substantially enlarged program of empirical studies, involving direct observation of behavior at the level of the individual and the organization, and including both laboratory and field experiments, will be essential in sifting the wheat from the chaff in the large body of theory that now exists and in giving direction to the development of new theory. Expanded research on expert systems will require extensive empirical study of expert behavior and will provide a setting for basic research on how ill-structured problems are, and can be, solved. â⬠¢ Decision making in organizational settings, which is much less well understood than individual decision making and problem solving, can be studied with great profit using already established methods of inquiry, especially through intensive long-range s tudies within individual organizations. The resolution of conflicts of values (individual and group) and of inconsistencies in belief will continue to be highly productive directions of inquiry, addressed to issues of great importance to society. â⬠¢ Setting agendas and framing problems are two related but poorly understood processes that require special research attention and that now seem open to attack. These five areas are examples of especially promising research opportunities drawn from the much larger set that are described or hinted at in this report. The tools for decision making developed by previous research have already found extensive application in business and government organizations. A number of such applications have been mentioned in this report, but they so pervade organizations, especially at the middle management and professional levels, that people are often unaware of their origins. Although the research domain of decision making and problem solving is alive and well today, the resources devoted to that research are modest in scale (of the order of tens of millions rather than hundreds of millions of dollars). They are not commensurate with either the identified research opportunities or the human resources available for exploiting them. The prospect of throwing new light on the ancient problem of mind and the prospect of enhancing the powers of mind with new computational tools are attracting substantial numbers of first-rate young scientists. Research progress is not limited either by lack of excellent research problems or by lack of human talent eager to get on with the job. Gaining a better understanding of how problems can be solved and decisions made is essential to our national goal of increasing productivity. The first industrial revolution showed us how to do most of the worldââ¬â¢s heavy work with the energy of machines instead of human muscle. The new industrial revolution is showing us how much of the work of human thinking can be done by and in cooperation with intelligent machines. Human minds with computers to aid them are our principal productive resource. Understanding how that resource operates is the main road open to us for becoming a more productive society and a society able to deal with the many complex problems in the world today. [pic] How to cite Simon Decision Making, Papers
Sunday, May 3, 2020
Efficient Market Hypothesis Vs Behavioural Finance free essay sample
Efficient Market Hypothesis vââ¬â¢s Behavioural Finance An efficient market is one in which share prices quickly and fully reflect all available information, where investors are rational, and there are no frictions. Investors determine stock prices on the basis of expected cash flows to be received from a stock and the risk involved. Rational investors should use all the information they have available or can reasonably obtain, including both known information and beliefs about the future. In an efficient market there is ââ¬Å"no free lunchâ⬠: no investment strategy can earn excess risk-adjusted average returns, or average returns greater than are warranted for its risk (Barberis, 2003). Market efficiency is assessed by determining how well information is reflected in stock prices. In a perfectly efficient market, security prices quickly reflect all available information and investors are not able to use available information to earn excess returns as it is already incorporated in prices. We will write a custom essay sample on Efficient Market Hypothesis Vs Behavioural Finance or any similar topic specifically for you Do Not WasteYour Time HIRE WRITER Only 13.90 / page The hypothesis that says security prices reflect all available information thus making it difficult for investors to make abnormal returns is the efficient market hypothesis (EMH). The foundations of EMH rest on three basic arguments 1) investors are assumed to be rational and hence they value securities rationally, 2) to the extent that some investors are not rational, their trades are random and hence cancel each other out ultimately having no effect on prices, and 3) if investors are irrational, they will be met in the market by rational arbitragers who will eliminate any influence they have on the market (Lawrence, McCabe Prakash, 2007).
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)